Bernmaster wrote: ↑Thu Nov 16, 2023 6:06 am
1. According to my understanding one big advantage is the reduction in turnover which minimizes transaction costs. This appears not to be the case for bond funds. Weights automatically adjust to price changes but bonds constantly fluctuate in and out. How much does this turnover cost fund holders in return?
Any buy-and-hold strategy minimizes turnover (and so the low turnover advantage is not limited to market weighting per se)...
so long as assets don't enter or leave the market in question.
In fact, stock index funds also suffer a similar issue, albeit to a smaller degree, as stock units enter and leave the stock market in question (e.g., companies issuing new stocks or doing buybacks, new companies entering the S&P500 or being delisted).
If the underlying assets mature, such as bonds do, then holding the asset class over longer than the maturity will necessitate buying new issues when the olds ones mature. Presumably bond funds can mitigate turnover by using fund inflows and outflows as rebalancing opportunities (just as an individual investor would rebalance using new income or by selling appropriately if they needed to sell anyway to meet cashflow needs). Either way, this is not specifically an issue with market weighting. Rather, it's an issue with holding an asset class longer than the maturity of the assets.
Bernmaster wrote: ↑Thu Nov 16, 2023 6:06 am
2. Another fact I'm struggling with is that in contrast to stocks the return of bonds is known at the purchase date if held to maturity (barring default). This appears not to be the case for bond funds. How predictive is the "yield to maturity" or "yield to worst" figure depicted in the fund prospectus of actual fund performance if held for the average duration of the fund?
There are two separate points you bring up here.
- The first is that the payoff predictability of bonds is greater than that of stocks. We pay for this predictability with lower expected return. This point is more about stocks vs bonds. It is not specifically about bond funds or market weighting.
- The second point is that the published statistics of bond funds are not as precise as individual bonds since they are aggregate / averaged statistics. They are lossy statistical summaries of the distribution of bonds in the fund. This is not related to market weighting or even bond funds, specifically. Most fund-level statistic (stock or bond) will be somewhat lossy, informationally speaking (e.g., PE ratio of S&P500).
Bernmaster wrote: ↑Thu Nov 16, 2023 6:06 am
3. Another point I struggle with is the "investment grade" requirement which forces the fund to sell bonds that get downgraded below BBB rating. I believe the bond funds are also forced to sell bonds when they reach less than one year of duration. To my understanding this is a drag on performance but can it be quantified?
This issue is not exactly unique to bonds. Stock indexes also have
criteria that are subjective judgement calls (e.g., minimum market cap, minimum trading volume). That said, I agree that the BBB rating cutoff of the Bloomberg aggregate bond index (AGG) is annoying. Personally, I hold junk bonds (at market weight) to partially fill in that gap. AGG doesn't include TIPS or municipal bonds either (for tax management reasons, I think). Again, this is not an issue with market cap weighting, but rather to any fund (bond or stock) that has arbitrary quality thresholds that assets can drift across. E.g., an equal-weighted fund with quality thresholds would have the same issues (perhaps even more so).
Bernmaster wrote: ↑Thu Nov 16, 2023 6:06 am
4. Could you please explain to me why market cap weighting works for bonds? Does a market cap weighted bond fund maximize risk-adjusted returns? Is the market portfolio for bonds "special" from a risk-return perspective?
This is the heart of the question. In the simplistic mean-variance model used by Modern Portfolio Theory and its cousins, the market portfolio (consisting of
all competitively traded, easily exchangeable assets which includes
both stocks
and bonds), lies on the efficient frontier and is the so-called tangency portfolio. And all investors hold a linear combination of the risk-free asset and the market portfolio. There are numerous assumptions that are made in the simple theory (e.g., single-period returns, simplistic risk model, borrowing at the risk-free rate). But there are some analogous results for more general models, such as
long-term investing and
multi-factor risk models.
There are varying views on what assets comprise the "universe of investable assets" with respect to market-cap weighting. E.g., should one include government bonds since both lenders and ultimately borrowers are the public themselves, and so is net public interest zero? And what about illiquid investments like private equity and debt, and real estate? William Sharpe has a good discussion on this in "Components of the Market Portfolio" section of
Chapter 7 of his RISMAT book. That entire chapter is fantastic and worth reading.
Some people take a rigid definition of "market" (e.g., limit to a single exchange) whereas others consider all assets that can be bought and sold relatively easily (and thus be easily exchanged across multiple exchanges).
Anyway, my overall point here is that if we are looking at efficient frontier or risk-adjusted return optimization, we need to consider all assets that the public has access to. Market weighting is efficient only when all publicly accessible options are included. And even when it is efficient, it may not be optimal for an individual's particular consumption needs... Keep in mind that one's consumption stream is basically a negative asset, and so theoretically an individual investor should be looking at efficiency not just across all investment assets but also with their own personal negative asset (consumption) and positive asset (income/human capital).
But it's important to note that market weighting has additional advantages beyond finding an efficient portfolio that hold even when only a subset of the market is considered -- e.g., minimizing turnover (modulo assets entering and leaving the system), lower management fees and taxes, low exposure to information asymmetry (because we minimize trading), doing as well as the average actively managed dollar (see Sharpe's article on
The Arithmetic of Active Management). These advantages hold for bonds same as they hold for other asset classes. And this is why many investors use market weighting for bonds even if they don't hold their stock vs bond ratio at market weight. (I think this paragraph is the TL;DR answer to your overall question.)
Bernmaster wrote: ↑Thu Nov 16, 2023 6:06 am
Does a market cap weighted bond fund maximize risk-adjusted returns? Is the market portfolio for bonds "special" from a risk-return perspective?
No, but neither does it do so for stocks. A market-weighted portfolio lies on the efficient frontier only when the
all alternative assets are considered (including both bonds and stocks). If you omit some alternatives that the market has access to, you no longer can rely on market weighting to optimize anything. Other benefits of market weighting listed above still hold, however.
But if you want to have the efficient frontier theoretical justification of on your side, you need to hold market weights across both stocks and bonds (and anything else you believe to be part of the publicly investable universe). And if you want to adjust for personal circumstances, you'd build a liability matching portfolio to transform your personal income and consumption stream into that of the dollar-weighted average investor, and then invest your remaining money in the market portfolio.
Bernmaster wrote: ↑Thu Nov 16, 2023 6:06 am
5. Even John Bogle seemed to have struggled with the the concept of market cap weighting for bonds which is evident from his suggestions in "The Little Book of Common Sense Investing" on how to improve returns by adding more corporate bonds. Is the credit and term risk of the bonds in a Total Bond Market fund appropriately compensated for and do the funds capture these risk premia?
The question of inclusion of government bonds (as opposed to corporate bonds) within a bond index is an interesting question. Sharpe discusses this in RISMAT Chapter 7 that I linked above. Read it, and decide for yourself where you stand. Personally, I take the same position as Sharpe that government debt is an investment in future human capital (via future taxpayer earnings).
For corporate bonds, some interesting food for thought is the
Modigliani-Miller theorem which says that, frictions aside, public claim to a companies earnings are independent of its capital structure (i.e., whether it chooses to fund its activities through issuing stocks or bonds) and dividend policy. This might justify holding both stocks and corporate bonds together at market weight.
Another wrinkle to consider is international bonds and the inescapable currency hedging that comes built into most international bond funds. But keep in mind that currency hedging affects only return, but not market weight. Personally, I just use global market weighting and hope that the built-in currency hedging in the fund's return mitigates the need for home-country bias in the global asset weighting.
AA = global stocks & bonds @ market weight (~60/40); EF = i-bonds; WR = -PMT(1%, 100-age, 1)